GATT and Third World Pharmaceuticals

INFORMATION ABOUT INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS No. 2

by Azra Talat Sayeed

July 1994

The Uruguay Round of General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) will hinder the Third World from attaining self sufficiency in pharmaceutical production. Low-income consumers will be saddled with higher prices when they attempt to buy essential medicines. They will also discover that many life saving medicines are simply not available. This will happen because Third World drug manufacturers will be discouraged from entering production, or forced out of business altogether, by pharmaceutical transnational corporations (TNCs).

Negotiators of GATT addressed Trade Related Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) agreements in great detail, but little attention was paid to the needs of the people of the Third World. The need for local firms to develop home-based expertise and capital was ignored. The Uruguay Round also shifted legal protections further in the favor of TNCs.

Burden of Proof

One of the most potent powers granted to TNCs in the Uruguay Round is the placing of the burden of proof in patent disputes on Third World manufacturers. Article 34 states: "... if the subject matter of a patent is a process for obtaining a product, the judicial authorities shall have the authority to order the defendant to prove that the process to obtain an identical product is different from the patented process." This places Third World firms at great risk for patent suits by TNCs because they do not have the resources to defend themselves. The accused manufacturer must demonstrate that it has not violated process patents TRIPS.

The TRIPs agreement protects a product patent for 20 years from the date of filing and then extends another 20 years protection to the manufacturing process if the process is new. Once a product patent has expired, other manufacturers can also manufacture a given product. However, if the manufacturing process is still under protection, the new entrant needs to develop an alternative production process. The burden of proof is on the secondary manufacturer to show that their new process is in fact unique.

Small firms may not be willing to enter the market for fear of legal action. If such producers stay out of the market, monopolies already present will become more powerful in the Third World drug trade. This lack of competition will increase prices and lower customer service. To make Article 34 fair, the burden of proof should rest on the accuser and not the accused.

High Prices

The present placement of the burden of proof on the accused will severely limit the capacity of the indigenous pharmaceutical industry to compete with TNCs. Already, the pharmaceutical industry requires huge capital investments and expensive product promotions, so little place is available for indigenous industries to create market share for themselves. Pharmaceutical TNCs will be able to create monopolies resulting in extremely high prices of medicines in the Third World.

Argentina offers a powerful example. Nearly all pharmaceuticals marketed by Argentinean drug firms are now sold at a prices ranging from 15-80 % lower than global corporation prices.1 This is the opposite of 15 years ago, when the Argentinean industry was just getting a foothold.2 With local market loyalties and efficient production, these firms can now provide low cost pharmaceuticals to the public. In addition, Argentina has a small export market for pharmaceuticals. The Argentinean pharmaceutical industry built a strong presence by locally producing and marketing drugs to the public at prices much lower than those of the TNCs. They were able to do so by defying and ignoring international patent systems created and promoted by the European nations and the United States. This allowed the Argentineans to compete with transnational pharmaceutical firms and also forced the transnational corporations to provide their products at competitive prices. Following are some price differentials in pharmaceutical products between the Argentinean and US markets3 :

Active Ingredient US Market (US$) Argentinean Market (US$)

Brand Name Foreign or Licences Domestic

Producers

Ciprofloxacin 106.82 14.20 13.15

Ketoconazole 240.05 36.10 26.65

Ranitidine 84.23 21.95 11.76

A similar experience can be seen in the case of India. India, using its compulsory licensing clause, allowed for the development of a national pharmaceutical industry. The indigenous industry has been capable of producing many essential drugs for its people at affordable prices. This would no longer be possible under the Uruguay Round. In fact, the independence of the Indian pharmaceutical industry has already been seriously undermined through unilateral trade measures taken by the United States4; a thrust which was largely brought about by the intervention of the US pharmaceutical industry. India has now changed its patent laws to conform with most of the US demands. Consequently, Indian manufacturers will no longer be able to provide affordable drugs to Indian consumers. Compare what India was able to do for its people with its domestic patent laws through a price comparison between products available in the Indian and Pakistani markets5:

Drug India (Indian Rs.) Pakistan (Indian Rs.) US (Indian Rs)

Ciprofloxacin 51.00 234.63 305.21

Ketoconazole 43.00 221.96 673.67

Ranitidine 29.30 260.40 744.65

The Burden of Costs

The Third World has already paid a price to comply with U.S. patent protections in many ways. The following problems need to be addressed.

Non-use of a patent: In many cases, TNCs will apply for a patent in a particular country but will not actually set up manufacturing facilities. This means the drug itself is imported, but not the production process. As a result of the patent protection local firms cannot enter into production. These imported patented products are more expensive and negatively impact the balance of trade of a developing country. Article 27 of the TRIPS agreement will further extend this very leeway to corporate business. The wording of the article is as follows:

". . . patent shall be available and patent rights enjoyable without discrimination . . . whether products are imported or locally produced."

It is imperative that the above clause be reevaluated due to its immense negative impact on the balance of trade of Third World countries. By producing products within the territories of a Third World country, the process would not only transfer technology (the basic premise for awarding patent protection), it also would provide a job market for the local population.

Licensing and Process Agreements: When TNCs do license their production processes to Third World manufacturers, they often do not allow their licensees to export products to other countries. Such agreements are not considered "barriers to trade" under GATT, though they certainly serve to restrict access of pharmaceuticals to many markets. Moreover, if employees at a Third World plant improve the product to bring about an innovative product, they usually are required to grant all patent rights back to the parent company6 so legal benefits stay in the hands of First World corporate owners. Further, many process agreements ban the establishment of research and development facilities by the licensee, charge excessive royalties, or force the Third World firm to buy inputs from the patent holder.7 Each of these limits the opportunity to develop indigenous industries and transfers wealth out of the Third World.

Transfer Pricing: Pharmaceutical TNCs will sell products (patented and otherwise) to their subsidiaries at prices that are 87-2,900% higher than found in open markets.8 This allows subsidiaries to show a net loss on their accounts thereby evading taxes in host countries. At the same time, subsidiaries will buy ingredients such as sugar from the parent company at excessive prices. Such manipulation of these prices has a negative impact on the balance of trade for Third World countries. If patents were abolished, then indigenous firms would be free to purchase all products from open markets, and hence not suffer such severe price manipulation.

Without the patent protection of the TRIPs agreement, TNCs would be willing to set up joint ventures with indigenous firms as they want access to markets even at the expense of sharing profits. This would allow indigenous firms to gain access to more sophisticated technologies and products which might not be available otherwise.

In short, it can be seen that patents in general benefit the TNCs and stifle the growth of industry in the Third World. Patent protection has never been able to provide the transfer of technology, especially for the Third World. The GATT agreement on TRIPs creates a far more stifling arrangement. There is no reason to believe that it will generate any benefits to the developing world.

Sources

1 Pablo M. Challu. The consequences of pharmaceutical product patenting. World Competition, December 1991, Vol. 15 No. 2. 2 Daniel Chudnovsky. The challenge by domestic enterprises to the transnational corporations' domination: A case study of the Argentine pharmaceutical industry. World Development, Vol. 7, pp. 45-58, 1979. 3. Pablo M. Challu. The consequences of pharmaceutical product patenting. World Competition, December 1991, Vol. 15 N0. 2., p. 107. 4 The unilateral trade measure is taken through The Omnibus Trade and Competitiveness Act of 1988. The act's Super 301 provisions allow the United States Trade Representative to undertake trade investigations and identify nations that enact trade practices against the US which are 'unreasonable' or 'unjustifiable.' The identified countries are obliged to alter those practices or suffer a loss of trade with the US. 5 B.K. Keayla & Biswajitt Dhar. Indian Pharmaceutical Industry and Patent Regime for Drug Security, in Patent regime in TRIPs. National Working Group on Patent Laws. September 1993, pp. 14-16. 6 Owen T. Adikibi. The multinational corporation and monopoly of patents in Nigeria. World Development. Vol. 16, No. 4, pp. 511-526, 1988. 7Arman S. Kirim. Reconsidering patents and economic development: A case study of the Turkish pharmaceutical industry. World Development Vol. 13, No. 2, pp. 219-236, 1985.

8 Gary Gereffi. The phamaceutical industry and dependency in the Third World. Princeton University Press, 1983.

For further information please contact:

Azra Talat Sayeed

7-115 HSUF

Graduate Studies in Social and Administrative Pharmacy University of Minnesota

308 Harvard Street S.E.

Minneapolis, MN 55455

Phone No.: (612) 624-1198

Fax No. : (612) 625-9931

------------------------------------------------

One in a series of info sheets on Intellectual Property Rights available from the Institute for Agriculture and Trade Policy. For a complete listing send email to: ipr-info@iatp.org