Share this

The following is the address delivered by Joachim von Braun, director-general of the IFPRI, at the WTO Public Symposium "Multilateralism at a Crossroads," Geneva, May 25, 2004. The International Food Policy Research Institute seeks sustainable solutions for ending hunger and poverty. IFPRI is one of the 15 Future Harvest Centers and receives its principal funding from 62 governments, private foundations, and international and regional organizations known as the Consultative Group on International Agricultural Research.

It has become a cliche that we live in an interconnected world, but cliche or not, globalization in its many and complex dimensions is one of the defining facets of our times.

To make economic globalization work smoothly, sovereign countries need a rules-based trading system sustained with transparency and clarity through multilateral institutions such as the WTO [World Trade Organization]. Since much of the world is impoverished, the rules of global trade must work as effectively for the poor as the rich, if the system is to be credible. One can hardly overstate how high the stakes are, that it do so.

Multilateralism is truly at a crossroad. Prompted partly by a lack of progress in the WTO negotiations, a host of bilateral trade negotiations are in progress. Bilateral agreements among large players lead to further marginalization of excluded low-income countries. In this global setting, restoring the effectiveness of multilateralism through the WTO is essential. Doing so will rest in the coming decade both on the substance of its rules and on the transparency and inclusiveness of the process through which they are achieved. Countries emerging as centers of global growth, and poor countries large and small, will only buy into a rules-based world trade system if they are brought into making its decisions. The new rules of the game must be written jointly by rich, middle-income, and poor nations, not just by a few powerful members.

Most of the world's poor depend on agriculture for a key part of their livelihoods. The future of about 350 million small farms and the people employed by them in low- and middle-income countries around the world depends upon improved access to well-functioning markets. Food and nutrition security of the poor is much affected by market and trade reforms in agriculture, as IFPRI [International Food Policy Research Institute] research has pointed out. Thus, agriculture is a critical sector in which a rules-based global trade system must work to the benefit of the poor. Yet, agriculture has long been treated as an exception to the rules, as a special case left outside the trade-liberalization process. As a result, extensive subsidies and border protection continue to block opportunities for those poor people who can best make their livings from farming and value-added farm products. If the poor remain losers in agricultural trade, then the trade rules adopted cannot be justified and WTO effectiveness and credibility will be impaired.

We focus on five steps that must be taken to make agricultural trade liberalization work for the poor, and we emphasize the need to combine trade policy reform with development investment to create level playing fields.

1. Developed countries must reduce their farm-sector support and border protection.

Support policies and border protection of the wealthy OECD [Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development] countries, worth hundreds of billions of dollars each year, cause harm to agriculture among developing countries. These policies include price guarantees, income support measures, and input-related and crop insurance subsidies that stimulate farm production. They also include tariffs and tariff-rate quotas (TRQs) that restrict market access and export subsidies that move high-priced farm products into world markets. The support and border protection policies of the developed countries are "special and differential treatment" for the rich not the poor.

Recent research at IFPRI and elsewhere illustrates the impacts of these policies. By blocking market access and driving down world prices for agricultural commodities, developed country policies reduce agricultural exports from the developing world by $37 billion (25%) annually, according to estimates by researchers at IFPRI. Agricultural GDP (value-added) among developing countries is reduced by $23 billion annually. For specific countries and specific commodities, the effects can be critical, as in the case of cotton for the rural poor in a number of African countries, or when Guatemala and other poor countries sell sugar at depressed world prices. IFPRI research presented to the WTO panel in the ongoing case by Brazil against US cotton subsidies analyzed the effects of lower world prices on poverty in cotton export-dependent Benin. Based on detailed household survey information, the results show that a drop of world cotton prices by 20% - as might occur due to developed country subsidies - raises poverty by four percentage points (an increase of 10% in the population in poverty) through direct and indirect effects on rural incomes.

Developed countries must end this harm to farmers in the developing world. Because they provide such large subsidies and so much protection, the developed countries must be the first to "come to the table" to offer real reforms in the Doha negotiations.

2. Developing countries must also open their markets.

Nearly one-third of the agricultural trade of developing countries is with other developing countries and this share is growing. But these countries also have substantial trade barriers on agricultural products. Among large developing countries, such as Brazil, China, India and Mexico, tariffs applied to agricultural products average more than 25%-these are higher tariff levels than imposed by many low-income countries. Developing country governments that are united in seeking the benefits from reduced agricultural subsidies and protection in the rich countries have been divided about what to do about their own agricultural trade barriers. Those countries with strong agricultural export potential have called for more open markets, but those fearful of negative effects on their poor farmers, including among agricultural exporters, have been reluctant to endorse such moves. Many civil society organizations and development advocates are adamant that developing countries be granted room to retain agricultural trade barriers.

Research confirms that what is at stake in reduction of agricultural protection among developing countries is somewhat different than the stakes from developed country reforms. When developing countries join in agricultural trade liberalization, research at IFPRI estimates their overall GDP gains are nearly $40 billion annually. This is more than twice the gain in developing country GDP (of $14.5 billion) when only the developed countries undertake agricultural reforms. The developing country trade policy reforms add an additional $15 billion annually to their aggregated agricultural exports. The additional gains come primarily because food consumers face lower internal prices as countries' own trade barriers are reduced-food consumers benefit in more countries when developing and developed countries reduce agricultural trade barriers.

Trade policy reforms among developing countries, thus, boost their overall income and agricultural exports. But it also creates distributional impacts between those developing countries that are best able to gain from trade openness versus those less able to do so. The benefits from reduced trade-distorting subsidies and border protection globally will not be universal or evenly distributed among poor countries. Targeted assistance policies will be needed for some countries or regions and population groups, particularly among the very least developed, whose agricultural resources and other circumstances do not leave them well positioned to benefit under new trade rules for agriculture. This includes the need for attention to price instabilities in low-income countries which may hurt the poor, especially when markets are not functioning well, and the step-wise phasing out of food aid dependencies in some countries. The need for targeted assistance should, however, not be an excuse for failing to make changes that create agricultural trade opportunities.

To achieve trade-based gains, developing countries that will benefit from more open markets abroad, especially middle-income developing countries, need to be forthcoming in opening their own markets. They, too, must come to the table to offer reforms in the Doha Round. As trade barriers are reduced, benefits for poor farmers, and additional gains for food consumers, in countries less able to compete on a global level will come not from multilateral trade policy reform by itself, but from complementary domestic investments and policy improvements, so called "behind the border" reforms-a point we will return to below.

3. A hollow Doha Round agreement on agriculture must be avoided.

The Uruguay Round created the first comprehensive framework of multilateral disciplines on agricultural subsidies and trade policies. It achieved only modest agricultural trade liberalization. Thus, the Uruguay Round legacy rests on whether it created the conditions for deeper subsequent reform. The question today is whether the Doha Round can deliver on that potential. New coalitions of developing countries play a much larger role in trade and in the negotiations over trade rules in the Doha Round. They stood up to a weak proposal for agriculture in Cancun to make it clear that the Doha Round must not end with a "Blair House" type of US-EU bilateral agreement as marked the close of the Uruguay Round. But will the Doha Round deliver?

As hard as it is proving to reach even a framework agreement in 2004, the negotiating texts in circulation leave room for concern about how much agricultural trade liberalization will be achieved in the Doha Round. Export subsidies are one of the most egregious interventions, prompting calls for protection abroad from such unfair competition. Export subsidies have cost over $5 billion in recent years, 90% of which is by the European Union. Full elimination of export subsidies would fulfill what was perhaps an implicit future promise from the Uruguay Round agreement. The indirect forms of export subsidization, through credit discounts and guarantees, misuse of food aid, and discriminatory pricing policies by state trading enterprises, are harder to measure, but these subsidies also need to be ended. Eliminating direct and indirect export subsidies would send a strong signal of multilateral commitment to imposing new disciplines on agricultural trade distortions. It would make it easier for other countries to lower tariff barriers.

In the complex area of domestic support policies, the developed countries face internal political pressure not to give up too much in a Doha agreement. The magnitude and instrumentation of domestic farm support policies are at issue.BusinessWorld: